Earlier this year,
Russia decided to occupy Crimea. Since then, the international community has
responded to this flagrant violation of international norms by condemning the
action and imposing various sanctions on Russia. However, some have called for
military intervention, leading many to wonder if sanctions are a strong enough
response to such aggression.
The idea of economic
sanctions being a practical, liberal alternative to war has become increasingly
common. Economists, such as Gary Hufbauer and Daniel Drezner support the idea
that sanctions have potential to be highly effective, while others, such as
Robert Pape, consider sanctions to be fairly useless overall. Regardless of
one’s personal belief over the usefulness of sanctions, nations do tend to
favor sanctions as a first step in coercing or dissuading another country from
objectionable behavior.
One way to determine the
potential effectiveness of sanctions is by using the Conflict Expectations
Model, designed by Drezner. In his book, “The Sanctions Paradox: Economic
Statecraft and International Relations” Drezner explains the model in details
and uses various case studies to test his hypothesis.
|
Low Expectation of Conflict:
|
High Expectation of Conflict:
|
Large Gap in Costs:
|
Significant Concessions
|
Moderate Concessions
|
Small Gap in Costs:
|
No Attempt at Sanctions
|
Minor Concessions
|
From this model, Drezner
makes the argument that by calculating the expectation of conflict and how much
the sanctions will hurt, it is possible to determine the level of success that
can be achieved through the implementation of sanctions. In the instance of
North Korea, sanctions have not brought about the desired results (namely the
elimination of its nuclear weapons program), but this can largely be attributed
to the fact that America is the main proponent of sanctions, yet has very
minimal economic ties to North Korea. Using Drezner’s model, it becomes
apparently that because North Korea has a high expectation of future conflict
and would only incur a small gap in costs from sanctions, the most that the
U.S. could reasonably hope for would be minor concessions.
However, it is important
to realize that if a targeted country can secure any of the sanctioned goods
from another country aside from the sender country, the sanctions will not be
as effective. Therefore, sanctions are generally more successful when applied
multilaterally. In the case of Russia, Drezner believes that no economic sanction
will compel Russia to leave Crimea because of a lack of unity regarding the sanctions, the
demanded outcome (a withdrawal from Crimea) is too high a price for Russia, and
because it will take time for Russia to feel a substantial impact from the
sanctions (and during that time Russia will likely try to establish the current
situation as the status quo). Despite this, Drezner believes sanctions should
still be leveraged against Russia as an attempt to deter it from repeating this
action and because sanctions can be a factor in the solution, even if they are
not a complete solution alone.
However, sanctions do
not always work, and according to Robert Pape, they rarely work. Pape
approaches sanctions from a very narrow perspective and only examines the
stated goal of sanctions when determining how successful they were. He further
asserts that in reality, it is ultimately the threat of war that often causes a
change in behavior.
Nevertheless, sometimes
the real policy goals or objectives are not explicitly stated and even if the
success rate is fairly minimal, the chance to avoid or lessen the severity of a
war by first pursuing economic coercion is worth it. Furthermore, Drezner’s
analysis of economic coercion from Russia towards thirteen post-Soviet states
appears to disprove the theory that military threats have a higher success
rate. Drezner notes that in regards to achieving its goals, “when military
power was threatened or exercised, Russia succeeded only 35.7 percent of the
time; when economic statecraft was the sole coercive mechanism, the success
rate was 80.0 percent.” While this is only a study of Russia vs. former-Soviet
states, it does provide solid examples of multiple instances where economic
coercion was more successful than military threats.
Another argument against
the use of sanctions is that they create a humanitarian crisis. Broad, severe
sanctions could certainly do that, but smart sanctions are a way to avoid such
an undesirable result. By freezing assets, imposing visa bans, implementing
arms embargoes, etc, a sender country is able to target
the demographic that it wishes to hurt the most. Specifically, if the
leaders of a country are most affected by sanctions, they are more likely to
reconsider their decisions.
Part of adequate defense
statecraft comes from understanding when it is necessary to go to war, and when
it is best to pursue other options, even if they initially appear unrelated to
defense or if they seem to indirectly affect military options. Economic
statecraft presents a different, but valid perspective when contemplating
military action. Economically, politically, and diplomatically isolating a
country can have powerful ramifications that will cause the targeted country to
reexamine its behavior. If sanctions help avoid a war, then lives have been
saved. If it still becomes necessary to turn to armed conflict, then so be it,
but it is imperative to explore all other options as well.
No comments:
Post a Comment